Should we specialise or diversify? Questioning the comparative advantage theory..

Happy New Year to all once again. Hope you had a great time last night. Fireworks in some places was as always brilliant. But I particularly liked the lightning in Shanghai which was different and looked really cool.

So how should ME start the new year? By pointing to an article that questions one of the oldest theories in economics – comparative advantage. It is by Prof Ricardo Hausmann of Harvard who has been writing some fascinating and food for thought stuff recently.

Comp Adv. theory says countries gain from trade by specialising in the good/service in which they hold comparative adv. Prof Hausmann says much talk about importance of specialisation is a myth. The more diversified an economy the richer it is.

He begins saying it is really hard to defy an idea that looks really good on paper:

Some ideas are intuitive. Others sound so obvious after they are expressed that it is hard to deny their truth. They are powerful, because they have many nonobvious implications. They put one in a different frame of mind when looking at the world and deciding how to act on it.

One such idea is the notion that cities, regions, and countries should specialize. Because they cannot be good at everything, they must concentrate on what they are best at – that is, on their comparative advantage. They should make a few things very well and exchange them for other goods that are made better elsewhere, thus exploiting the gains from trade.

But, while some ideas are intuitive or obvious, they can also be wrong and dangerous. As is often the case, it is not what you don’t know, but what you mistakenly think you know, that hurts you. And the idea that cities and countries actually do specialize, and that therefore they should specialize, is one of those very wrong and dangerous ideas.

When an idea is both intuitively true and actually false, it is often because it is true on one level but not on the level at which it is being applied. Yes, people do specialize, and they should specialize, too. Everyone benefits from each of us becoming good at different things and exchanging our knowhow with others. It is not efficient for a dentist and a lawyer, for example, to be the same person.

But specialization at the individual level actually leads to diversification at a higher level. It is precisely because individuals and firms specialize that cities and countries diversify.

He points to examples from countries:

The scale at which specialization of individuals leads to diversification is the city. Larger cities are more diversified than smaller cities. Among cities with similar populations – say, Salvador and Curitiba in Brazil, or Guadalajara and Monterrey in Mexico – more diversified cities are richer than less diversified cities. They tend to grow faster and become even more diversified, not only because they have a larger internal market, but also because they are more diversified in terms of what they can sell to other cities and countries.

\What is true at the level of cities is even more applicable at the level of states and countries. The Netherlands, Chile, and Cameroon have a similar population size, but the Netherlands is twice as rich as Chile, which is 10 times richer than Cameroon. Looking at their exports shows that the Netherlands is three times more diversified than Chile, which is three times more diversified than Cameroon.

As my colleagues and I recently argued, one way to understand this is to think of industries as stitching together complementary bits of knowhow, just as words are made by putting together letters. With a greater diversity of letters, the variety of words that can be made increases, as does their length. Likewise, the more bits of knowhow that are available, the more industries can be supported and the greater their complexity can be.

So the richer regions do not specialise but diversify:

In the process of development, cities, states, and countries do not specialize; they diversify. They evolve from supporting a few simple industries to sustaining an increasingly diverse set of more complex industries. Achieving this implies solving important coordination problems, because an industry that is new to a city will not find workers with industry experience or specialized suppliers. But policymakers can do a lot to solve these coordination problems.

This is why the idea that cities, states, or countries should specialize in their current areas of comparative advantage is so dangerous. Focusing on the limited activities at which they currently excel would merely reduce the variety of capabilities – or “letters” – that they have. The challenge is not to pick a few winners among the existing industries, but rather to facilitate the emergence of more winners by broadening the business ecosystem and enabling it to nurture new activities.

This is all the more important today, because the globalization of value chains is delocalizing supplier-customer relations. Cities and countries would be ill-advised to focus on a few “clusters” and consolidate the value chains in their location, as is so often recommended. Instead, they should worry about being a node in many different value chains, which requires finding other industries that can use their existing capabilities if they were somehow expanded and adjusted to new needs.

Strong words…But a cracker of a start to the new year as it questions how most economics textbooks start. It is a non-trivial issue surely..

About these ads

One Response to “Should we specialise or diversify? Questioning the comparative advantage theory..”

  1. Jorge Morales Meoqui Says:

    Prof. Hausmann’s article might contradict the so-called the Ricardian trade model of contemporary economic textbooks, but it does not contradict the two propositions which Ricardo originally wanted to illustrate with his famous numerical example: 1) that his labor theory of value does not regulate the relative value of commodities in international exchanges when the factors of production (capital and labor) are less mobile across country borders than within these borders; and 2) that a country might import a certain quantity of a commodity although it can produce it with less amount of labor time than the exporting country.

    https://www.academia.edu/1948311/Comparative_advantage_and_the_labor_theory_of_value

Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out / Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out / Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out / Change )

Google+ photo

You are commenting using your Google+ account. Log Out / Change )

Connecting to %s


Follow

Get every new post delivered to your Inbox.

Join 1,175 other followers

%d bloggers like this: